Dr Kamilla Marchewka-Bartkowiak

Money Theory and Monetary Policy Department

The Poznan University of Economics

Poland

 

Government debt management

- institutional arrangements in selected countries and in Poland

 

 

JEL Classification Number: H63

Keywords: government debt management, institutional arrangements, pubic debt management agency

Corresponding Address:

Kamilla Marchewka-Bartkowiak, PhD - tel. +48 603 136 765,

e-mail: kamilla.bartkowiak@ue.poznan.pl

 

 

Introduction

         Government (public) debt management is today one of the most important areas of public finance reforms in most countries in the world. Especially intensive changes have been taking place in the European Union member states. The process gathered momentum after 1999, with the creation of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Major international institutions, such as the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, the OECD, or the European Central Bank have been quite emphatic about the importance of government debt management worldwide. They release regular reports on each state’s developments in public debt management, issue guidelines on the fundamentals of government asset and liabilities management policy making, promote publications and analyses on public debt management quoting experiences of selected countries.

One of clue areas of undertaken reforms was the institutional arrangement of government debt management and the direction to change the central banking or ministerial model into the public agency model.

         Polish reforms of public debt management go back in principle to the early 1990s. The reforms have affected the majority of functions of this section of budget policy, changing the statistics, accounting, and operations, as well as organisational framework of the Treasury securities market. Public management reforms undertaken in Poland have resulted to a large extent from a negative dynamics of budgetary indicators and the necessity of adjusting to the European Union standards. However, there are still significant barriers of institutional and also political character, which in the future can make government debt management and budget objectives difficult to achieve.

 

Government debt management – definition and functions

In a traditional aspect public finance policy is divided into monetary policy (money) and fiscal policy (income and expenses). The main criteria of the division is the realized aims, institutional solution, fulfilled functions and range of utilised instruments.

The above determinants influence the differentiation between the two mentioned areas of public operations. They currently have a significant meaning in marking off the public debt management policy.

The analysed financial field can be considered microeconomic aspect through institutional and operational research as well as macroeconomic aspect through researching the impact of an established way for the government budget indebt management on government decisions, central bank and other entities.

The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank define public debt management as a process of realizing adequate worked out strategies for obtaining appointed amount of funds and reaching the goals associated with debt cost and risk, as well as fulfilling goals through development and maintaining profitable and liquid public security market[1].

In the OECD publications public debt management is defined  as a degree of realizing four categories of goals, which are as follows: fulfilling the public lending needs, minimising debt servicing costs, upholding all kinds of risk on acceptable level and the development of internal capital market[2].

Public debt management realizes public assumptions set, therefore it is also classified as part of the government budget policy.

In this aspect the main goals of government debt management, concerning mainly the level of financing the shortages in the budget planned by the government in a given year (or in a long term prognosis), are defined by respective government departments (The Ministry of Finance, The Treasury).

It has to be underlined at this point that the level of the capability to be indebted by a government can be limited by conditions of higher institutions (international) as it is the case in Economic and Monetary Union - EMU (budget deficit and the public debt criteria – Maastricht Treaty[3] and Stability and Growth Pact[4]).

Adequate government institutions (The Ministry of Finance, The Treasury) can put up limits (level of tolerance) in cost scale, or risk in servicing public debt (New Zealand for example). However, the above goals are frequently set according to suggestions laid by the government debt management institutions. In this case there are different Committees (strategic, management risk etc) internally established to deal with the matter and are responsible for formulating strategies in various areas of institutional activities or a group of consultants consisting of  representatives of indicated institutions, ministries, parliament, private sector or academicians who meet periodically to advise and suggest on policy formulation. An example of the first organizational solution whose role is among others to formulate and set debt management goals is the Belgian Strategic Committee, consisting of the following: The Treasury Administrator General, representatives of the Ministry of Finance and directors of three Directorates of public debt agency. Groups of consultants also function in such countries as Australia, France, Ireland, the United Kingdom and New Zealand.[5]

In as far as market operational goals are concerned, the most common strategy and procedure are set by the management itself. This applies to the amount of public debt servicing costs as well as implementing appropriate assumptions concerning policy about different types of risks, which may appear in a stated period. Above all detailed goals about the functioning of public securities market are defined.

The market characteristics of the government budget financing, especially the increasing role of risk management in public portfolio instruments forces the necessity of providing control and auditing operations. In case of public debt servicing risk, the management institution undergoes an operation based on multi-criteria analysis of factors determining the change. Controlling the appropriate choice of risk estimation methodology, realization of established procedures and respecting set limitation, at the same time know-how among the management workforce on how to utilize optimal solutions in the topic, although it is a basic element of the process management in case of public finance it should undergo comprehensive monitoring.[6]

The achievement of adopted public debt management goals for a year or longer term basis must be depended not only on high level of financial reports, but on evaluation which has to guarantee indispensable transparence, thereafter creditability of the stated policy.

From the entity’s point of view, the verification indicated should be carried out at a number of levels: by the government (stating the goal), in internal operation of the public debt management institution (stating and realizing the goals) and through an external, independent organization (state control department or an auditing company). From the subjective point of view it should cover action in the institutional and functional control as well as external and internal audit.[7]

Currently, the importance of an autonomy in public debt management institution is underlined, due to participating on equal rights basis in the financial market. Great attention is paid to issues concerning political and operational independence which would guarantee the highest degree of realization of goals and public debt management strategy in the medium and long term.

Taking into consideration the latest tendency concerning institutional solutions of public finance, it is proved that public debt management is activated by and put into force legally and carrying out its responsibilities and function for the government. It realizes ready made internal goals and strategies through market operations.

The most important functions of government debt management covers two types of fields laid out in below table.

 

Table 1. Functions of government debt management

Policy formulation and planning function

Public securities market organization function

· accomplishment of the established policy through target formulation, instrument adjustment, coordination of monetary policy and approbation of public indebtedness,

· planning, including forecasting future public lending needs and formulating programs of their financing,

· fiscal function, within liquidity management of the government budget including future money flows forecast,

· advisory function.

 

·        organising and managing the primary market,

·        issuing function, i.e. organising and selecting issuing procedures,

·        organising secondary market through expanding its liquidity and depth,

·        administrative function (settlement and deposit).

 

 

Source: Based on L. Kalderen, Debt Management Functions and Their Location, V. Sandararajan, P. Dattels, Public Debt and Monetary Management in Transition Economies in: V. Sandararajan, P. Dattels, H.J. Blommenstein, Coordinating Public Debt and Monetary Management, IMF, 1997

 

         Principles and characteristics of the above mentioned functions of public debt management pay attention to what has been formulated by the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund publications on the topic[8], where these international institutions, basing on experiences of member countries, also present propositions of applying clear control and monitoring policy as well as annual external audit[9].

         It is observed that the identification of the problem which should be in the competence range of public debt management has an essential meaning when identifying external and internal formula (model) of the institutional organization of the public debt management. Therefore, taking into consideration the optimal quartering of functions within the given institution, a division is proposed below[10]:

• financial source mobilization function – all operations dealing with drawing up and implementing plans of financing budget deficits on both domestic and foreign markets are involved in this range,

  indebtedness and risk analysis function – covering portfolio analysis of owing instruments, risk management strategy and financial indebtedness scenery formulation, as well as identifying and valuating benchmark portfolio,

• information and settlement system management function.

         The above study clearly emphasizes the classification of functions usually used by financial institutions dealing with market operations. In their scope of operation additional tasks in form of controlling appear.

        

Government debt management in European Union

The accession to the European Union intensified public debt reforms in respect of both the policy and the necessity to adjust the Treasury securities market infrastructure. The subsequent changes will be determined for the most part by the development of public debt management in the countries of the old EU which have been at the forefront of this field, and the extent of the reforms effected by other Central and Eastern European countries, including their consecutive accessions to the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). 

         The underlying problem in all the member states is posed by the increasing investor pool and reducing investment activities risk on the Treasury securities market. High government borrowing needs that predominate in most EU countries contribute to a high level of competition and constantly introducing new management and market solutions. In the Economic and Monetary Union member countries, where the interest rates are similar (the EBC reference rates) activities of a nature other than the price are of a special importance.

         The most notable issues which will require the EU public debt managers to constantly modify the various areas of their responsibility include:

-         changes in the portfolio with more emphasis on investor preferences,

-         the development of methods of optimising Treasury securities portfolio and risk analysis and forecasting methods,

-         the modification and development of issuance methods,

-         improved information policy and investor relations,

-         development of the geographical range and distribution channels of Treasury securities,

-         increased use of operations on debt components and derivatives,

-         increased efficiency of settlement system,

-         minimisation of participation costs for investors in the primary  and secondary Treasury securities market (i.al. intermediary costs),

-         the introduction and developments of various segments of the secondary Treasury securities market,

-         and the introduction of and/or development of the agency model of public debt management institutional framework,

 

Institutional arrangements of government debt management

          Generally accepted formulation – government debt management institution – applies to the principles of the functioning of world institutional models. Taking into consideration the evolution and experience of different countries, three main[11] solutions in the researched field could be observed: 

ministerial model:

-         debt management functions are situated in the government ministerial structure (in one or more departments),

-         debt management objectives are indicated and realized in budget goals,

banking model:

-         debt management function are within the range of the central banking structure,

-         public debt management (objectives, strategy, operations) are subordinate to overriding monetary objectives,

agency model:

-         public debt management function are concentrated in one independent institution or within the structures of other entities,

-         high level of operational transparency guarantees normalises legal and responsibility range and wide information policy,

-         operational objectives and debt management strategy are worked out and realized within an agency under a ministerial approbation,

-         multi-level auditing and control of agency operation.

       A critical view of the first two models that has appeared for some time now, mainly concerns dependence of debt management objectives and strategies on fiscal or monetary objectives, has led to the fact that practically a mixed model is commonly applied due to the public debt management status and localization[12]. Institutional solution in analysed countries is presented in the table below.

 

Table 2. Institutional division criteria of the public debt management solutions of selected countries

 

 

 

 

 

 

Status criteria

Separate legal act normalizing functional principles of an independent public debt management institution (government agency, joint stock company with government shares)

 

Ireland

Germany

Sweden

Hungary

 

Internal document stating the status of public debt management agency in a ministerial structure with a range of responsibilities.

Belgium

France

The Netherlands

The UK

Australia

New Zealand

 

Separating a department concentrating on public debt management function

Denmark

Finland

Italy

Poland

Slovenia

Spain

Japan

Lack of public debt management department

 

Canada

* bold – EU countries

Source: Based on information from the selected countries

 

The least effective of all is placing individual basic public indebtedness management function in different institutions – ministry, central bank, commercial banks and others. Decentralization usually concerns tasks connected with domestic and foreign debt management, government budget liquidity management, management of other government obligations, issuing organization, or settlement functions. Therefore, there is need to stress that concentrating basic operational functions in one separate public debt management agency is currently both a postulate of international institutions (IMF, World Bank, OECD) and also a market requirement.

         After analysing the specification in table 2, a straight forward way can be established regarding the domination of the agency model (table 3 – the agency model in selected EU countries). Localization agency in an overriding institution (ministry, central bank), or in a different building (city) seem to have less meaning. For participants of the capital market, a distinct status for public debt management institution is an information of great importance. It creates a basis for a greater respect among investors in as far as operational effectiveness is involved and transparency in realized policy.

In the analysed countries, ten of them have agencies whose function is based on distinct legal records, stating their form, scope of responsibility and hierarchy. In four cases – Ireland, Sweden, Germany and Hungary- there are institutions which are separately located, in  which the first two have a government agency nature, the rest are public stock companies.

Denmark[13] is a specific case where the transferring of tasks concerning government indebtedness management in 1991 from the ministry of finance to the central bank took place due to recommendations from the government auditors. They postulated the change taking into consideration the necessity of strict coordination between currency reserve management and  government foreign debt. Apart from that, attention was paid to the benefits of the specialized personnel and a wide access as well as well organized market operations conducted by the central bank. Currently, emphasis is clearly laid on the meaning of formal and informal coordination principle between debt management and monetary policy in Denmark, as well as high degree of transparency in the conducted policy, based on large, evident and frequent information, detailed reporting and operations in the control and audit scope.

The mixed model also points at other additional solutions which are due to a negative assessment. One of the examples is Canada, where public debt management is under the Department of Finance without a clear separation within the ministry of finance structure. On the other hand the Polish example can be applied due to an especially separated Public Debt Department, which does not concentrate on basic public debt management tasks. Decentralization deals with the division of functions in domestic and foreign debt management, liquidity or contingent liabilities management within different ministerial departments.    

To sum up it can be stated that public debt management agency has become a modern standard government institution on a world scale and in EU countries.

 

 

 

Table 3. Government debt management agency model in selected EU countries                                                                                    

Country

Name of agency

Date of establishment

Sweden

Swedish National Debt Office

1789

The Netherlands

Dutch State Treasury Agency

1841

Ireland

National Treasury Management Agency

1990

Belgium

Belgian Debt Agency

1998

The UK

UK Debt Management Office

1998

 

Germany

German Finance Agency

2000

France

Agence France Trésor

2001

Source: Based on information from the selected countries

 

The case of Poland[14]

         Poland is still one of the EU country with the ministerial model of government debt management but with separated department.

Generally, pursuant to the stipulations of the Acts on public finance and earlier regulations, the Finance Minister as the Treasury agent is responsible for managing the State Treasury debt, as well as issuing Treasury securities. His duties also include controlling the state of public debt, and controlling the public finance sector’s compliance with the annual debt limits.  According to the last Act the Finance Minister’s main tasks include undertaking legal and actual activities aimed at raising funds to finance the state budget borrowing needs, servicing the State Treasury liabilities resulting from issued securities, and contracted loans and credits,  as well as managing the state budget’s liquidity and the State Treasury financial assets.

Due to the fact that the responsibility for public debt management has been transferred to the Ministry of Finance (and not the Treasury), a Public Debt Department was established in 1993 for the first time within the Ministry’s structure. The Department pursued management objectives concerned with the domestic debt. Managing foreign debt was delegated to the Foreign Department.  Additionally, guarantees and sureties were assigned to a separate Department of State Treasury Guarantees and Sureties, which has been operational to date. The division of tasks in the decision making existed until 1998, when foreign debt policy was consolidated with the Public Debt Department.  Four years later another reorganisation took place, which lead to the re-emergence of a separate foreign debt section. Lately a Department of State Assets and Liabilities was appointed to conduct all of the public debt policy operations (now as Public Debt Department).

The above analysis of the institutional framework of the unit directly responsible for public debt management suggests that the organisational scope is rather volatile, with an ill-matching organisational and functional structure.  The solutions are in line with the so called ministry model, whose main features are the lack of differentiating the entity’s status or the scope of its operational independence (including the institutional one) and a total submission of management activities to the current aim of budget policy. 

With a view to co-ordinating public debt management with monetary policy the Public Debt Management Committee was set up in 1994 to act as an opinion making and advisory body. This organ is an important platform for exchanging opinions between the Ministry of Finance and the NBP, and is frequently used in the institutional frameworks in many countries around the world.

 

Conclusion

Agency model of government administration is now is one of the standard in government debt management in the many countries, including euro area. Effective agency solutions is especially noticeable, including mainly the internal organisational structure fit to market operations, the scope and type of supervisory activities (internal audit of public debt management), personnel policy, benefits resulting from focusing the management of all assets and liabilities of state budget in one unit, the possibility of conducting management activities aimed at reducing the debt of other public finance sector entities.

 Poland is facing a challenge posed by the accession to the euro zone. This now irrevocable decision will have several consequences.  The most important ones will be first of all boosted stability and consistency in pursuing budget policy including government debt and its cost which is growing component of budget expenditures and deficit. One of the most important directions is the institutional reform of government debt management.

 

 

Biography

1.           Anderson P., Should public debt be managed by a separate agency? in: Government Debt Management: New Trends and Challenges, ed. by M. Willians, P. Brione, Central Banking Publications, London 2006

2.           Currie E., Dethier J-J., Togo E., Institutional arrangements for public debt management, World Bank Policy Research Working Papers 3021, April 2003

3.           Dattels P., Public Debt and Monetary Management in Transition Economies in: V. Sandararajan, P. Dattels, H.J. Blommenstein, Coordinating Public Debt and Monetary Management, IMF, 1997

4.           Debt Management and Government Securities Markets in the 21st Century, OECD 2002

5.           Government debt management: new trends and challenges, ed. M. Williams, Central Banking Publications, London 2006.

6.           Guidelines for Public Debt Management: Accompanying Document, IMF and the World Bank, November 2002

7.           Guidelines for Public Debt Management, IMF and the World Bank, December 2003

8.           Golebiowski G., Marchewka-Bartkowiak K., Audit and control in public debt management (Polish version), Working Papers of National Bank of Poland No 181/204

9.           Kappagoda N., Institutional Framework for Public Sector Borrowing, UNITAR, Geneva, No 17/2002

10.       Maastricht Treaty, 1992

11.       Marchewka-Bartkowiak K., Government debt management, The scope of reforms undertaken and constraints on further development in Poland, Better Government Programme, Ernst&Young 2006

12.       Marchewka-Bartkowiak K., Institutional aspects of coordination between public debt management and monetary policy (Polish version), Bank i Kredyt, National Bank of Poland, No 10/2003

13.       Marchewka–Bartkowiak K., Public debt management. Theory and practice in the EU countries (Polish version), PWN, Warszawa 2008

14.       Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), 1997 (change in 2005)

15.       Wheeler G., Sound Practice in the Government Debt Management, The World Bank, Washington 2004

16.       Williams M., The growing responsibilities of debt management offices, in:

Kalderen L., Debt Management Functions and Their Location, V. Sandararajan, P. Dattels, H.J. Blommenstein, Coordinating Public Debt and Monetary Management, IMF, 1997

 

 

 



[1] Guidelines for Public Debt Management: Accompanying Document, IMF and the World Bank, November 2002

[2] Debt Management and Government Securities Markets in the 21st Century, OECD 2002, p. 51

[3] Maastricht Treaty, 1992

[4] Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), 1997 (change in 2005)

[5] K. Marchewka-Bartkowiak, Institutional aspects of coordination between public debt management and monetary policy (Polish version), Bank i Kredyt, National Bank of Poland, No 10/2003, p. 4-13

[6] More in: G. Golebiowski, K. Marchewka-Bartkowiak, Audit and control in public dent management, Working Papers of National Bank of Poland No 181/204

[7] Ibidem

[8] Guidelines for Public Debt Management, IMF and the World Bank, December 2003

[9] More on the topic see: E. Currie, J-J. Dethier, E. Togo, Institutional arrangements for public debt management, World Bank Policy Research Working Papers 3021, April 2003

[10] N. Kappagoda, Institutional Framework for Public Sector Borrowing, UNITAR, Geneva, No 17/2002

[11] More on this topic see : Marchewka–Bartkowiak K., Public debt management. Theory and practice in the EU countries (Polish version), PWN, Warszawa 2008

[12] See more: G. Wheeler, Sound Practice in the Government Debt Management, The World Bank, Washington 2004 or P. Anderson, Should public debt be managed by a separate agency? in: Government Debt Management: New Trends and Challenges, ed. by M. Willians, P. Brione, Central Banking Publications, London 2006, p. 79-92, Williams M., The growing responsibilities of debt management offices, w: Government debt management: new trends and challenges, ed. M. Williams, Central Banking Publications, London 2006.

[13] Debt Management Office of Danmarks Nationalbank

[14] K. Marchewka-Bartkowiak, Government debt management, The scope of reforms undertaken and constraints on further development in Poland, Better Government Programme, Ernst&Young 2006