Ýêîíîìè÷åñêèå
íàóêè / Ìàêðîýêîíîìèêà
Cand. of Science in
Economics Taranenko I.V.
Donetsk
State University
THE
KONDRATIEV’S CYCLES AS A BASIS OF INNOVATION STRATEGIES AT GLOBAL ECONOMY
Under the conditions of the world system’s transition to the globalization
- and - innovation stage of post-industrial development at the turn of the XX
century, the strategies of countries’ competitiveness should be developed
taking into account the cyclic world dynamics. A prominent sociologist and
economist Nikolay Kondratiev established linkage between the large cycles and the processes of stock accumulation and the
dynamics of innovations [1]. The explanation of «Kondratiev’s cycles» through the
“waves of technological innovations” was developed in works of Joseph Shumpeter,
Alfred Kleinknecht, Gerhard O. Mensh, Christopher Freeman and others.
Although Kondratiev waves time limits are still being under the
discussion [2], it is important to separate Kondratiev cycle upwave and
downwave stages for compare it with globalization periods. So the upwave stage
of the 1st Kondratiev cycle (1785/90–1844/51) took the
period from the end of 1780-s – beginning of 1790-s till 1810 – 1817. Ascending stage of 2nd Kondratiev cycle (1844/51–1890/96) N. Kondratiev determined is marked as
1844/51 – 1870/ 1875. The prosperity
stage of the 3rd long cycle covered 1890 – 1896/1914 – 1920 years.
Kondratiev’s
followers propose to determine the limits of the 4th and 5th
cycles’ ascending stages accordingly as 1939 – 1950/1968 – 1974 and 1984 – 1991/2005 – 2008 [2, p. 190].
The principle stages and
historical types of globalization interpreted by British historian Antony
Hopkins [3], Ukrainian researcher of globalization problems Anton Filipenko [4,
p. 19], experts of the World Bank [5] and Organization of Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) are generalized in Table 1.
Table 1
Generalization of
the points of view to the stages and types of globalization
Antony
Hopkins |
Anton
Filipenko |
World Bank |
OECD |
Archaic Globalization |
Archaic (Low-intensity) Globalization: trade of ancient civilizations and
middle-age states |
- |
- |
Proto-
Globalization 1600
– 1800 |
Proto-
Globalization: the period of Great Geographic Discoveries, World market formation,
beginning of industrialization (XV-XVI cent. - till the beginning of Õ²Õ
cent.* |
- |
- |
Industrial Globalization: 1800 – middle of ÕÕ cent. |
Modernistic
Globalization: transition of the society to
modernization and industrialization as a result of scientific and industrial
revolutions (first quarter of Õ²Õ cent. – second half of ÕÕ cent.)* |
First
wave of Globalization:
1870-1940 |
First stage of Globalization - internalization (activization of export flows): from the
middle of Õ²Õ cent. |
Post-colonial Globalization: 1950 – 1970 -s |
Second
wave of Globalization: 1950
– 1980 |
Second stage of Globalization – transnationalization (activization of
FDI flows): after 1945 |
|
Modern Globalization: after 1970 |
Post-colonial (organic, consistent) form of globalization: elimination of colonial system (1950-1970-s), disintegration
of USSR and East Block
(1990-s.)* |
Third wave of Globalization: from 1980-s |
Third stage – exactly Globalization: from 1980-s |
Composed by [3, 4, 5]
The comparison of time limits of Kondratiev’s long
cycles with the stages or «waves» of
globalization given in Table 1 demonstrates the considerable coincidence of
globalization processes acceleration with upwave stages of Kondratiev’s cycles.
This coincidence has to be considered through the prism of J. Shumpeter’s
thesis about the exclusive role of innovations in causing long cycles of
business activity.
Such a statement leads to an
assumption that innovative processes expand by different way in different
phases of a long cycle. G. Mensh has determined that an economy is most sensitive
to innovations in the period of depression [6]. According to the research of C.
Freeman, the development of innovative processes takes place in the period of
recovery [7]. The research carried out by A. Poletaiev and I. Savelieva shows
that the periods of maximum number of basic innovations coincide with the
depression phases of the world long cycle [8, p. 45]. The study of dynamics of the world leading companies’
expenditures on research and development (B. Yaruzelskiy and C. Dehoff) showed
a 5,7% growth of such expenditures during the world financial and economic
crisis in 2008-2009, in spite of a 8,6% decrease of operational income and a
34% fall of net profit [9, p. 3]. More
than two thirds of the companies included in 2009/2010 Global Innovation 1000
maintained or increased R&D spending in 2008. Furthermore, the analysis
revealed that innovation investment is increasingly viewed as essential to
corporate strategy: More than 90 percent of executives surveyed said innovation
is critical as they prepare for the upturn. “Innovation is what drives our
competitive position in all three of our markets — automotive, professional,
and consumer — and therefore we can’t back off,” says Robert Lardon, corporate
vice president for strategy and investor relations at Harman International Industries
Inc. Adalio Sanchez, general manager of IBM’s System X server business, echoes
that point of view: “I would argue that the recession is a catalyst for
increased innovation” [9, p. 4].
Therefore, we can assume that the time of
«starting» the innovative process covers a considerable period during the
depression and recovery phases. In turn, the Japanese scientist M. Hirooka
proved that the diffusion of innovations takes place simultaneously with the
upwave stage of Kondratiev’s cycle [10].
The results of scientific
research allow to assume that innovative competitive advantages are formed on
the descending (downwave) stage of Kondratiev’s large cycle, whereas the
diffusion of innovations takes place on the ascending (upwave) stage of the
«long wave». The ascending stage of Kondratiev’s long cycle is characterized by
favorable conditions for profiting from competitive advantages provided by
integration and globalization.
The discovery of the relations between the dynamics of globalization and
innovation processes in the world economic system, the determination of a
correlation between the periods of globalization processes acceleration and
definite phases of Kondratiev – Shumpeter’s «long waves», as well as
determination of peculiarities of
innovative processes implementation on particular phases of the long cycle lay
down the foundations for developing strategies of competitiveness for economic
entities’ – enterprises (companies), regions, countries and international
integration groups.
On the descending stage of
the long cycle the formation of innovative competitive advantages through
companies’ management and government’s assistance to the innovation process is
of particular importance.
Such policy will result in
the creation of conditions for an «innovation jump» and efficient
implementation of innovative model of economic development for the countries
which are highly integrated into the global economy, on the ascending stage of
the cycle. The realization of innovative competitive advantages, in turn,
creates conditions for stimulating the participation of separate companies and
countries in the process of global integration on the basis of partnership on
the growth stage. Thus, the integration competitive advantages can be used most
efficiently on the ascending stage of Kondratiev’s cycle. The data of the world
globalization dynamics for the period of 1980 – 2000 prove the above statement.
The economists argue that the
ascending phase of the Kondratiev’s fifth cycle ended in 2005-2008 whereupon
the world economy entered the depression phase which will probably last from
2010 to 2020 [2,
p. 237]. This period is the most favorable for «starting up» a
new wave of innovation activity directed at the development and implementation
of innovations at the global level.
The
period from 2010 to 2020 considered as a descending stage of Kondratiev’s fifth
long cycle is the most favorable for stimulating the innovation activity,
especially in the countries integrated into the global economy. The approach
proposed above may be applied in Ukrainian economy for develop innovation
strategy at post-crisis period.
References:
1. Êîíäðàòüåâ Í.Ä. Áîëüøèå öèêëû êîíúþíêòóðû è òåîðèÿ ïðåäâèäåíèÿ. / Í.Ä. Êîíäðàòüåâ. - Ì.:
Ýêîíîìèêà. - 2002. – 768 ñ.
2.
Êîðîòàåâ À.Â. Êîíäðàòüåâñêèå
âîëíû â ìèðîâîé ýêîíîìè÷åñêîé äèíàìèêå / Êîðîòàåâ À.Â., Öèðåëü Ñ.Â. //
Ñèñòåìíûé ìîíèòîðèíã: Ãëîáàëüíîå è ðåãèîíàëüíîå ðàçâèòèå / Îòâ. Ðåä. Ä.À.
Õàëòóðèíà, À.Â. Êîðîòàåâ. – Ì.: Êíèæíûé äîì «ËÈÁÐÎÊÎÌ», 2010. – 296 ñ.
3.
A. G. Hopkins, Globalization in World History. /
A.G. Hopkins - W. W. Norton, 2002.
4.
Ôèëèïåíêî À.Ñ. Ýêîíîìè÷åñêàÿ
ãëîáàëèçàöèÿ: èñòîêè è ðåçóëüòàòû / À.Ñ. Ôèëèïåíêî. – Ìîñêâà: Ýêîíîìèêà, 2010 –
511 ñ.
5.
Globalization, Growth and
Powerty: Building an Inclusive World Economy. A World Bank Policy Research
Report. / The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. — Oxford University Press. — 2002. – 192 P.
6.
Mensch G. Stalemate in
Technology – Innovations Overcome the Depression. / Mensch G. - New York, NY:
Ballinger. - 1979
7. Freeman C. Technical Innovation, Diffusion and Long Cycles
of Economic Development. / Freeman C. / The Long- Wave Debate / Ed. by T.
Vasko. Berlin: Springer. P. 295-309
8. Ïîëåòàåâ À.Â. «Öèêëû Êîíäðàòüåâà» â èñòîðè÷åñêîé ðåòðîñïåêòèâå
/ Ïîëåòàåâ À.Â., Ñàâåëüåâà È.Ì. – Ì.: ÇÀÎ «Þðèäè÷åñêèé äîì
«Þñòèöèíôîðì», 2009. – 272 ñ.
9.
Jaruzelski B. Profits Down,
Spending Steady: The Global Innovation 1000. / B. Jaruzelski, K. Dehoff. //
Strategy + Business.- Issue 57. - Winter 2009, Reprint number 09404. – 14 P.
10. Hirooka M. Innovation dynamism and economic growth. A
non-linear Perspective. / M. Hirooka. – Cheltenham, UK-Northampton, MA :
Edward Elgar , 2006.