INFLATION ACCOUNTING

 

PhDr. Miroslav ŠKODA, PhD.,

University of Matej Bel, Faculty of Economics, Department of Finance and Accounting,

Tajovského 10, Banská Bystrica, 974 01, Slovakia, tel. 00421 48 446 63 25,

email address: miroslav.skoda@umb.sk

 

 

Abstract

While the use of fair value as a measurement attribute for purposes of financial statement display has become increasingly popular in recent years, accounting principles — both most national GAAP and IFRS — still remain substantially grounded in historical costing.  Notwithstanding that under US GAAP a major pronouncement has established a hierarchy of fair value measurement techniques — and that a forthcoming IFRS standard is likely to do likewise, probably replicating the US GAAP standard — few or no new mandates to apply fair value accounting have been issued.

In periods of price stability, the use of historical cost information does not do much of a disservice to understanding the reporting entity’s financial position and results of operations.  However, in times of price instability — or, in the case of long-lived assets, even in periods of modest changes in prices over long stretches of time — financial reporting can be distorted.  Over many decades, a wide variety of solutions to this problem have been proposed, and, in certain periods of rampant inflation, some of these have even been put into practice.

 

Key words

Accounting, inflation, hyperinflation, price instability, IAS / IFRS, US GAAP

 

Introduction

Accounting practice today, on virtually a worldwide basis, relies heavily on the historical cost measurement strategy, whereby resources and obligations are given recognition as assets and liabilities, respectively, at the original (dollar, yen, etc.) amount of the transaction from which they arose. Once recorded, these amounts are not altered to reflect changes in value, except to the limited extent that various national GAAP standards or IFRS require recognition of impairments (e.g., lower of cost or fair value for inventories, etc.). Most long-lived assets such as buildings are amortized against earnings on a rational basis over their estimated useful lives, while short-lived assets are expensed as physically consumed. Liabilities are maintained at cost until paid off or otherwise discharged.

It is useful to recall that before the historical cost model of financial reporting achieved nearly universal adoption, various alternative recognition and measurement approaches were experimented with. Fair value accounting was in fact widely employed in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, and for some regulatory purposes (especially in setting utility service prices, where regulated by governmental agencies) remained in vogue until somewhat more recently. The retreat from fair value accounting was, in fact, due less to any inherent attractiveness of the historical cost model than to negative reaction to abuses in fair value reporting. This came to a climax during the 1920s in much of the industrialized world, when prosperity and inflation encouraged overly optimistic reflections of values, much of which were reversed after the onset of the worldwide Great Depression.

 

Historical Review of Inflation Accounting

The persistent inflation experienced by many industrialized nations during the 1960s, 1970s, and early 1980s caused there to be a reexamination of the long-held and widespread commitment to historical cost as the principal basis for financial reporting.  (An exception had been those nations, such as many in Latin America, where inflation had been endemic for many decades, and where price-level adjusted financial reporting was commonly employed.)  Popular interest in alternative techniques of inflation accounting (as the various methods are all called) declined markedly once price stability was restored, by the mid-1980s. Most of the financial reporting standards adopted (including those under US and UK GAAP, and under IFRS) have been revoked, made optional, or fallen into disuse during this time. As part of the IASB’s Improvements Project, IAS 15, the standard on inflation accounting, was withdrawn in 2005.

While the standard has been withdrawn, it does remain as a matter of record as one highly evolved set of guidance that entities can still utilize, should the decision be made to present supplementary financial statements on a basis which removes the effects of cost changes. For reporting entities electing to present inflation adjusted financial statements, this will continue to be instructive, together with selected literature published by US and UK standard setters and other bodies such as the US Securities and Exchange Commission. Thus, although presentation of inflation–adjusted financial statements is no longer required, for entities choosing to present such financial data, this guidance continues to be pertinent.

Most of what are known as generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) were developed after the crash of 1929. The more important of the basic postulates, which underlie most of the historical cost accounting principles, include the realization concept, the stable currency assumption, the matching concept, conservatism (or prudence), and historical costing. Realization means that earnings are not recognized until a definitive event, involving an arm’s-length transaction in most instances, has occurred. Stable currency refers to the presumption that a ˆ1,000 machine purchased today is about the same as a ˆ1,000 machine purchased twenty years ago, in terms of real productive capacity. The matching concept has come to suggest a quasi-mechanical relationship between costs incurred in prior periods and the revenues generated currently as a result; the net of these is deemed to define earnings.  Conservatism, among other things, implies that all losses be provided for but that gains not be anticipated, and is often used as an argument against fair value accounting. Finally, the historical costing convention was adopted as the most objectively verifiable means of reporting economic events.

The confluence of these underlying postulates has served to make historical cost based accounting, as it has been practiced for the past sixty years, widely supported. Even periods of rampant inflation, as the Western industrialized nations experienced during the 1970s, has not seriously diminished enthusiasm for this model, despite much academic research and the fairly sophisticated and complete alternative financial reporting approaches proposed in the United Kingdom and the United States and a later international accounting standard that built on those two recommendations. All of these failed to generate wide support and have largely been abandoned, being relegated to suggested supplementary information status, with which very few reporting enterprises comply.

What should accounting measure? Accounting was invented to measure economic activity in order to facilitate it.  It is an information system, the product of which is used by one or more groups of decision makers: managers, lenders, investors, even current and prospective employees. In common with other types of decision-relevant data, financial statements can be evaluated along a number of dimensions, of which relevance and objectivity are frequently noted as being the most valuable. Information measured or reported by accounting systems should be, on the one hand, objective in the sense that independent observers will closely agree that the information is correct, and on the other hand, the information should be computed and reported in such as way that its utility for decision makers is enhanced.

Objectivity has become what one critic called an occupational distortion of the accounting profession. While objectivity connotes a basic attitude of unprejudiced fairness that should be highly prized, it has also come to denote an excessive reliance on completed cash transactions as a basis for recording economic phenomena. However, objectivity at the cost of diminished relevance may not be a valid goal. It has been noted that “relevance is the more basic of the virtues; while a relevant valuation may sometimes be wrong, an irrelevant one can never be of use, no matter how objectively it is reached.” Both the FASB in the United States and the IASB in the international arena have published conceptual framework documents which support the notion that more relevant information, even if necessitating a departure from the historical costing tradition, could be more valuable to users of financial statements.

Why inflation undermines historical cost financial reporting? Financial statements that ignore the effects of general price level changes as well as changes in specific prices are inadequate for several reasons.

  1. Reported profits often exceed the earnings that could be distributed to shareholders without impairing the entity’s ability to maintain the present level of operations, because inventory profits are included in earnings and because depreciation charges are not adequate to provide for asset replacements.
  2. Statements of financial position fail to reflect the economic value of the business, because plant assets and inventories, especially, are recorded at historical values that may be lower than current fair values or replacement costs.
  3. Future earnings prospects are not easily projected from historical cost based earnings reports.
  4. The impact of changes in the general price level on monetary assets and liabilities is not revealed, yet can be severe.
  5. Because of the foregoing deficiencies, future capital needs are difficult to forecast, and in fact may contribute to the growing leveraging (borrowing) by many enterprises, which adds to their riskiness.
  6. Distortions of real economic performance lead to social and political consequences ranging from suboptimal capital allocations to ill-conceived tax policies and public perceptions of corporate behavior.

 

Example

A business starts with one unit of inventory, which cost ˆ2 and which at the end of the period is sold for ˆ10 at a time when it would cost ˆ7 to replace that very same unit on the display shelf. Traditional accounting would measure the earnings of the entity at ˆ10 – ˆ2 = ˆ8, although clearly the business is only ˆ3 “better off” at the end of the period than at the beginning, since real economic resources have only grown by ˆ3 (after replacing the unit sold there is only that amount of extra resource available).  The illusion that there was profit of ˆ8 could readily destroy the entity if, for example, dividends of more than ˆ3 were withdrawn or if fiscal policy led to taxes of more than ˆ3 on the ˆ8 profit.

On the other hand, if the financial report showed only ˆ3 profit for the period, there could be several salutary effects.  Owners’ expectations for dividends would be tempered, the entity’s real capital would more likely be preserved, and projections of future performance would be more accurate, although projections must always be fine-tuned since the past will never be replicated precisely.

 

Evolving use of financial statements

The failure of the historical cost statement of financial position to reflect values is yet another major deficiency of traditional financial reporting. True, accounting was never intended to report values per se, but the excess of assets over liabilities has always been denoted as net worth, and to many that clearly connotes value. Similarly, the alternative titles for the statement of financial position, balance sheet and statement of financial condition, strongly suggest value to the lay reader. The confusion largely stems from a failure to distinguish realized from unrealized value changes; if this distinction were carefully maintained, the statement of financial position could be made more useful while remaining true to its traditions.

The traditional statement of financial position was the primary, even the only, financial statement presented during much of accounting’s history. However, beginning during the 1960s, what is currently known as the statement of comprehensive income achieved greater importance, partly because users came to realize that the statement of financial position had become the repository for unamortized costs, deferred debits and credits, and other items that bore no relationship to real economic assets and obligations. In the aggressive and high-growth 1960s and early 1970s, the focus was largely on summary measures of enterprise performance, such as earnings per share, which derived from the statement of comprehensive income. During this era, the matching concept became the key underlying postulate that drove new accounting rules.

Following a series of unpleasant economic events, including numerous liquidity crises and recessions in the 1970s and 1980s, the focus substantially shifted back to the statement of financial position. Partly in response, the major accounting standard-setting bodies developed conceptual standards that urged the elimination of some of the items previously found on statements of financial position that were not really either assets or liabilities. Some of these were the leftovers from double entry bookkeeping, which was oriented toward achieving statement of comprehensive income goals (e.g., the optimal matching of revenues and expenses); an example is the interperiod tax allocations that resulted in the reporting of ever-growing deferred tax liabilities that were never going to be paid. While the tension between achieving a meaningful statement of financial position and an accurate statement of comprehensive income is inherent in the double-entry accounting model in use for almost 500 years, accountants are learning that improvements in both can be achieved. Inflation adjusted accounting can contribute to this effort, as will be demonstrated.

 

General vs. specific price changes

An important distinction to be understood is that between general and specific price changes, and how the effects of each can be meaningfully reported on in financial statements. Changes in specific prices, as with the inventory example above, should not be confused with changes in the general level of prices, which give rise to what are often referred to as purchasing power gains or losses, and result from holding net monetary assets or liabilities during periods of changing general prices. As most consumers are well aware, during periods of general price inflation, holding net monetary assets typically results in experiencing a loss in purchasing power, while a net liability position leads to a gain, as obligations are repaid with “cheaper” dollars. Among other effects, prolonged periods of general price inflation motivates entities to become more leveraged (more indebted to others) because of these purchasing power gains, although in reality creditors are aware of this and adjust interest rates to compensate.

Specific prices may change in ways that are notably different from the trend in overall prices, and they may even move in opposite directions. This is particularly true of basic commodities such as agricultural products and minerals, but may also be true of manufactured goods, especially if technological changes have great influence. For example, even during the years of rampant inflation during the 1970s some commodities, such as copper, were dropping in price, and certain goods, such as computer memory chips, were also declining even in nominal prices. For entities dealing in either of these items, holding inventories of these non-monetary goods (usually a hedge against price inflation) would have produced large economic losses during this time. Thus, not only the changes in general prices, but also the changes in specific prices, and very important, the interactions between these can have major effects on an enterprise’s real wealth. Measurement of these phenomena should be within the province of accounting.

Over the past fifty years there have been a number of proposals for pure price level accounting, financial reporting that would be sensitive to changes in specific prices, and combinations of these. There have been proposals (academic proposals) for comprehensive financial statements that would be adjusted for inflation, as well as for supplemental disclosures that would isolate the major inflation effects without abandoning primary historical cost based statements (generally, the professional proposals and regulatory requirements were of this type). To place the former requirements of the now-withdrawn standard IAS 15 in context, a number of its more prominent predecessors will be reviewed in brief.

At its simplest, price level accounting views any given currency at different points in time as being analogous to different currencies at the same point in time. That is, 1955 US dollars have the same relationship to 2008 dollars as 2008 Swiss francs have to 2008 dollars or euros.  They are “apples and oranges” and cannot be added or subtracted without first being converted to a common measuring unit. Thus, “pure” price level accounting is held to be within the mainstream historical cost tradition and is merely a translation of one currency into another for comparative purposes. A broadly based measure of all prices in the economy should be used in accomplishing this (often, a consumer price index of some sort is employed).

A number of proposals have been offered over the years for either replacing traditional financial statements with price level adjusted statements, or for including supplementary price level statements in the annual report to shareholders. In the United States, the predecessor of the current accounting standard setter, the Accounting Principles Board, proposed supplementary reporting in 1969; no major publicly held corporation complied with this request, however. The FASB made a similar proposal in 1974 and might have succeeded in imposing this standard had not the US securities market watchdog, the SEC, suggested instead that a current value approach be developed. (Later the SEC did impose a replacement costing requirement on large companies, and the FASB followed with its own version a few years thereafter.)

In the United Kingdom a similar course of events occurred. After an early postwar recommendation (not implemented) that there be earnings set aside for asset replacements, a late 1960s proposal for supplementary price level adjusted reporting was made, followed a few years later by a more comprehensive constant dollar recommendation.  As happened in the United States at about the same time, what appeared to be a private sector juggernaut favoring price level adjustments was derailed by governmental intervention. A Royal Commission, established in 1973, eventually produced the Sandilands report, supporting current value accounting and not addressing the reporting of purchasing power gains or losses at all. This marked the end of British enthusiasm for general price level adjusted financial statements. Even a fairly complex later proposal (ED 18) made in 1977 did not incorporate any measure of purchasing power gains or losses, although it did add some novel embellishments to what basically was a current value model.

Other European nations have never been disposed favorably toward general price level accounting, with the exception of France. However, Latin American nations, having dealt with virtually runaway inflation for decades, have generally welcomed this type of financial reporting and in some cases have required it, even for some tax purposes. While price level adjustments are no more logical in Brazil, for example, than in the United States, since specific prices are changing, often at widely disparate rates, the role of accounting in those nations, serving as much more of an adjunct to the countries’ respective tax collection and macroeconomic policy efforts than in European or other Western nations, has tended to encourage support for this approach to accounting for changing prices.

 

Current value models and proposals

By whatever name it is referred to, current value (replacement cost, current cost) accounting is really based on a wholly different concept than is price level (constant dollar) accounting. Current value financial reporting is far more closely tied to the original intent of the accounting model, which is to measure enterprise economic wealth and the changes therein from period to period. This suggests essentially a “statement of financial position orientation” to income measurement, with the difference between net worth (as measured by current values) at year beginning and year-end being, after adjustment for capital transactions, the measure of income or loss for the intervening period. How this is further analyzed and presented in the statement of comprehensive income (as realized and unrealized gains and losses) or even whether some of these changes even belong in the statement of comprehensive income (or instead, are reported in a separate statement of movements in equity, or are taken directly into equity) is a rather minor bookkeeping concern.

Although the proliferation of terminology of the many competing proposals can be confusing, four candidates as measures of current value can readily be identified:  economic value, net present value, net realizable value (also known as exit value), and replacement cost (which is a measure of entry value). A brief explanation will facilitate the discussion of the IAS / IFRS requirements later in this chapter.

Economic value is usually understood to mean the equilibrium fair market value of an asset.  However, apart from items traded in auction markets, typically only securities and raw commodities, direct observation of economic value is not possible.

Net present value is often suggested as the ideal surrogate for economic value, since in a perfect market values are driven by the present value of future cash flows to be generated by the assets. Certain types of assets, such as rental properties, have predictable cash flows and in fact are often priced in this manner. On the other hand, for assets such as machinery, particularly those that are part of a complex integrated production process, determining cash flows is difficult.

Net realizable values (NRV) are more familiar to most accountants, since even under existing US, UK, and international accounting standards, there are numerous instances when references to NRV must be made to ascertain whether asset write-downs are to be required.  NRV is a measure of “exit values” since these are the amounts that the organization would realize on asset disposition, net of all costs; from this perspective, this is a conservative measure (exit values are lower than entry values in almost all cases, since transactions are not costless), but also is subject to criticism since under the going concern assumption it is not anticipated that the enterprise will dispose of all its productive assets at current market prices, indeed, not at any prices, since these assets will be retained for use in the business.

The biggest failing of this measure, however, is that it does not assist in measuring economic income, since that metric is intended to reveal how much income an entity can distribute to its owners, and so on, while retaining the ability to replace its productive capacity as needed.  In general, an income measure based on exit values would overstate earnings (since depreciation and cost of sales would be based on lower exit values for plant assets and inventory) when compared with an income measure based on entry values. Thus, while NRV is a familiar concept to many accountants, this is not the ideal candidate for a current value model.

Replacement cost is intended as a measure of entry value and hence of the earnings reinvestment needed to maintain real economic productive capacity. Actually, competing proposals have engaged in much hairsplitting over alternative concepts of entry value, and this deserves some attention here. The simplest concept of replacement value is the cost of replacing a specific machine, building, and so on, and in some industries it is indeed possible to determine these prices, at least in the short run, before technology changes occur.  However, in many more instances (and in the long run, in all cases) exact physical replacements are not available, and even nominally identical replacements offer varying levels of productivity enhancements that make simplistic comparisons distortive. The next example shows what is discussed about.

 

Consider a machine with a cost of ˆ 40,000 that can produce 100 widgets per hour.  The current price of the replacement machine is ˆ 50,000 that superficially suggests a specific price increase of 25% has occurred. However, on closer examination, it is determined that while nominally the same machine, some manufacturing enhancements have been made (e.g., the machine will require less maintenance, will require fewer labor inputs, runs at a higher speed, etc.) which have altered its effective capacity (considering reduced downtime, etc.) to 110 widgets per hour. Clearly, a naive adjustment for what is sometimes called “reproduction cost” would overstate the machine’s value on the statement of financial position and overstate periodic depreciation charges, thereby understating earnings. A truer measure of the replacement cost of the service potential of the asset, not the physical asset itself, would be given as

ˆ 40,000 × (50,000/40,000) × 100/110 = ˆ 45,454

That is, the service potential represented by the asset in use has a current replacement cost of ˆ 45,454, considering that a new machine costs 25% more but is 10% more productive.

 

Consider another example: An integrated production process uses machines A and B, which have reproduction costs today of ˆ 40,000 and ˆ 45,000, respectively. However, management plans to acquire a new type of machine, C, which at a cost of ˆ 78,000 will replace both machines A and B and will produce the same output as its predecessors. The combined reproduction cost of ˆ 85,000 clearly overstates the replacement cost of the service potential of the existing machines in this case, even if there had been no technological changes affecting machines A and B.

 

Some, but not all, proposals that have been made in academia over the past sixty years, and by standards setters and regulatory authorities over the past twenty-five years, have understood the foregoing distinctions. For example, the US SEC requirements of the mid-1970s called for measures of the replacement cost of productive capacity, which clearly implied that productivity changes had to be factored in. The subsequent private sector rules issued by FASB seemed to redefine what the SEC had mandated to highlight its own current cost requirement; in essence, the FASB’s current costs were nothing other than the SEC’s replacement costs. Other proposals have been more ambiguous, however. Furthermore, measuring the impact of technological change adds vastly to the complexity of applying replacement cost measures, since raw replacement costs (known as reproduction costs) are often easily obtained (from catalog prices, etc.), but productivity adjustments must be ascertained by carefully evaluating advertising claims, engineering studies, and other sources of information, which can be a complex and costly process.

 

Conclusion

The experience of the international accounting standard that was designed to reveal the effects of inflation is very similar to the experiences in the United States and the United Kingdom.  That is, while there was a great clamor, primarily from the financial analyst community, in favor of this supplementary financial reporting model, once it was mandated there was a noticeable decline in interest. It would appear that analysts much prefer to develop their own estimates of the impact of inflation on the companies they follow and may have an inherent distrust of management-supplied data. As for management, it generally argued that such information was useless before the standard was imposed, which at the time seemed to be self-serving posturing in the hope that an expensive new mandate could be averted.

As in the United States, after a few years of mandatory presentation of supplementary inflation adjusted information (IAS 15 was imposed in 1981), the IASC announced in 1989 that presentation would no longer be required to comply with the standard, although it would still be encouraged. This status continued until the Improvements Project determined to eliminate the guidance entirely.

The Improvements Project concluded that IAS 15 was no longer needed and should be withdrawn. The IASB stated that, “the Board does not believe that entities should be required to disclose information that reflects the effects of changing prices in the current economic environment.” In the authors’ view, for those (few) entities which believe that inflation adjusted financial reporting continues to serve a useful purpose, the guidance in IAS 15 and in the foregoing discussion of this chapter continues to be germane.

 

References

1.      ŠURANOVÁ, Z. – ŠKODA, M. 2007. Medzinárodné účtovníctvo. Banská Bystrica: Ekonomická fakulta UMB, 2007. ISBN 978-80-8083-438-8

2.      International Accounting Standards (2000). ISBN 80-88715-89-X

3.      ŠURANOVÁ, Z. – SAXUNOVÁ, D. – KRIŠTOFÍK, P. 2004. Finančné účtovníctvo a riadenie s aplikáciou IAS/IFRS – I. diel. Banská Bystrica: Fakulta financií UMB, 2004. ISBN 80-8083-021-5

4.      Opatrenie MF SR č. 23054/2002-92 zo 16.decembra, ktorým sa ustanovujú podrobnosti o postupoch účtovania a rámcovej účtovej osnove pre podnikateľov účtujúcich v sústave podvojného účtovníctva

5.      Zákon č. 431/2002 Z. z. o účtovníctve v znení neskorších predpisov

  1. GROFČÍKOVÁ, J.: Koncepčné prístupy ku controllingu, jeho úlohy a význam pri riadení výkonnosti podniku, In: Diagnostika podniku, controlling a logistika, Zborník zo 4. medzinárodnej vedeckej konferencie(na CD nosiči) Fakulty prevádzky a ekonomiky dopravy a spojov, Žilinská univerzita v Žiline, Žilina, 17. – 18. 4. 2008, pp. 65 – 73. ISBN 978-80-8070-819-1

7.      MUSA, H. Determination of Financing Decision and Dividend Policy. In Zborník z medzinárodnej vedeckej konferencie (Finansowanie dziatalnosci przedsiebiorstw). Katowice-Poľsko: Wyzsa szkola bankowa Poznan 2005. ISBN 83-7205-215-8

8.      EPSTEIN, B. J. – MIRZA, A. A. 2008. Interpretation and Aplication of International Accounting Standards, WILEY, Rexdale, Ontario, Canada. ISBN 0-471-22736-6

9.      WARREN, C.S. – FESS, P.E. – REEVE, J.M. 1996. Accounting. South-Western Publishing Co., Cincinnati, Ohio, USA. ISBN 0-538-83644-X

10.  GRANOF, M.H. – BELL, P.W. – MAHER, R. C. 1996. Financial Acoounting – Principles and Issues. Prentice-Hall Inc., Scarborough, Ontario, Canada. ISBN 0-13-349911-1

11.  REWSINE, L. – COLLINS, D.W. – JOHNSON, W. B. 2002. Financial Reporting and Analysis. Prentice Hall Inc., Upper Saddle River, New Yersey, USA. ISBN 0-324-01565-8

12.  POTKÁNY, M. 2005. Účtovníctvo podniku ako zdroj informácií pre rozhodovacie úlohy v oblasti nákladov a cien. In: Dane a účtovníctvo v praxi 6/2005, Bratislava, IURA EDITION s.r.o., 2005, s. 58 – 60. ISSN 1335-7034

13.  PINTÉR, Ľ. 2005. Legislatívne a daňové aspekty v oblasti kolektívneho investovania po vstupe SR do EU. In: Finance a účetnictví ve vědě, výuce a praxi: sborník mezinárodní konference. Zlín, Univerzita Tomáše Bati. ISBN 80-7318-288-2