Prof. Andrzej Czyżewski, Dr. of Economics, University of Economics in Poznań

Sebastian Stępień,  Dr. of Economics, University of Economics in Poznań

 

The circumstances and directions of changes in Common Agricultural Policy

in the view of Health Check

 

Introduction

In the past years the Common Agricultural Policy in the European Union has undergone significant transformations due to progressing world-wide economic globalisation and liberalisation processes as well as the pressure of European society and international organisations. The incentive to changes was also the fact of growing support costs and too high budget commitments. As a result in the years 2003-2004 a deep reform of CAP was carried out which changed a lot of intervention mechanisms on the agricultural market and stating the shape of the CAP for the period of 2007-2013. Those targets where especially stressed which aimed at the EU agricultural market competitiveness growth on the world-wide market along with preserving the level of rural inhabitants incomes and natural environment safety. Therefore the agricultural policy was to support not only its productive function but also other non-productive functions creating the background for the multifunctional and sustainable farming i.e. providing the economic, social and environmental criteria[1].

Simultaneously on the basis of the agreement in force drew by the agricultural ministers of the EU-15 in Luxemburg of 26 June 2003 and the arrangements of the EU Board of 22 April 2004 the European Commission was obliged to evaluate the reformed agricultural policy functioning and its simplification[2]. In November 2007 the Commission published the announcement “Preparations to CAP functioning evaluation”, the same beginning the 6-month-period of formal consultations of that document with farming-related representatives of various circles. This review so-called “Health Check”, is to assess the CAP functioning and to make a proper correction of reformed instruments and as a result to pass a package of legislative acts concerning CAP along with the French presidency, it means in November-December 2008. It is extremely important time because the accepted solutions will be the issue of the EU budget in years 2009-2013 and in the next financial perspective of 2014-2020.

The main aim of this paper is to present the concepts of the EU agricultural basic support mechanisms directions’ changes accepted within “Health Check” review and their evaluation in view of the EU agricultural markets stabilisation. The authors will focus on those aspects of medium-term review which according to them are the most crucial to further Union agricultural development. They amount to the answers to the following questions:[3]:

 

The future of Single Payment Scheme

The direct subsidies are the basic instrument of the EU support and they should be considered in view of the public goods creation linked to the external effects existence. It is connected with the creation of rural areas multifunction and the agriculture itself[4]. The share of the  CAP payments grew in the EU budget in the past years which allowed to compensate partially the reduction of prices and to separate to some extent the support from the production. In the same time due to the growing world-wide competitiveness and trade liberalisation the demands for the agricultural producers changed and the payments mechanism followed transforming and started to take into consideration the environmental requirements, the animal wealthiness and good framing practice. During the debate within the medium-term union budget review the issues of Single Payment Scheme were broadly discussed. The sense of continuing the support as well as its shape were considered. Generally there is an agreement that further support is needed which can be explained with following arguments[5]:

·         in case of the I Pillar support abolition it can be expected that many of farms will not be able to function in free market. Mostly bigger farms with field crops and dairy products will become unable to create incomes in which the payments constitute a major part of the total income;

·         the abolition of payments will significantly weaken the EU agricultural competitiveness in the world. It is caused by the fact that the world price competitiveness of agri-food comes first of all from beneficial soil and climate conditions; in view of that the American production will gain the comparative advantages;

·         the risk caused by the Single Payment Scheme liquidation is connected with the supply reduction and the farming products price increase on the internal market which will be disadvantageous for the consumers. Moreover, this phenomenon can be of a progressive tax character because higher costs can be borne by households of the lowest incomes but the highest share of food expenditures;

·         moreover direct payments influence the production quality assurance and taking into consideration environmental requirements. Thanks to the payments the EU farmers can produce goods which fulfil the veterinary, sanitary and quality standards and for which the consumers’ demand continually grows. Thus the direct payments are the price which the society pay in exchange for the food safety (in a quantity and quality sense), as well as becoming independent from countries like the USA, Brazil or Argentina.

Negotiations on the direct payments additionally concerned further separation of payments from the magnitude and structure of agricultural production so-called decoupling[6] and system unification among the EU members. The first postulate should be considered a step in good direction because to a significant extent it eliminates the overproduction problem and allows the farmers to follow the signals from the market. In this sense we can consider „decoupling” as necessary to assure the economic effectiveness on the local as well as international market[7], and it also allows to strengthen the EU position on the WTO forum. Simultaneously the new mechanism requires form the rural households to obey strict rules of environment protection and animal wealthiness therefore the function of direst payments should be the producers’ compensation of lost incomes and costs borne linked to the realisation of a number of new public functions connected with the positive external effects of agricultural activity. It also seems right to unify the system and to move to one system (unified payment per household – SPS or payment per hectare – SAPS[8]), all the more that  farmers of all union member countries will be obliged to fulfil the same requirements regarding the environment and food safety (so-called cross-compliance), and the union support will depend on that. It seems the system of the EU means distribution which covers the historical level of production is unfair, especially from the point of view of new member states including Poland, therefore it is postulated to switch to regional model of single payments[9]. In a further perspective it can contribute to equal the competitiveness between the EU-15 countries and the new members and as well it will cause the simplification of procedures and it will be more farmer-friendly.

However it must be noticed that the decision of a single payments scheme change in the direction of unified payment will cause significant move of the EU budget redistribution (it is estimated that it will reach approx. 6-7 billion euro)[10].  The beneficiaries will be mostly new member states like: Romania, Bulgaria and Poland as well as poorer countries of “old” Union, i.e. Greece, Portugal, Spain. On the other hand the losses will be borne by those countries until now to a big extent used the European farming support like France and Germany. An objection can be expected from those countries while negotiating the shape of a future Single Payment Scheme. To convince them the it must be indicated that the proposed changes are complementary with CAP aims and this is a difficult task. Nowadays it is clearly visible that one of the main targets of the Union policy which s the support of countries of the lowest development level in view of the available data is not fulfilled. Such situation requires the renewal of a detailed debate on CAP aims and stating the instruments of the implementation.

 

The support of rural areas development via the modulation mechanism

The EU policy concerning rural areas evolved along with the CAP development. Initially it was focused on the structural problems in the agri-food production sector to become the policy concerning a different farming significance in the society regarding the implemented CAP reforms, especially the challenges which should be undertaken in a wider – social, economic and environmental context of rural areas. Already in 1999 during the agreements of Agenda 2000 it was pointed out that the significance of agricultural sector decreases and its non-productive significance increases: providing traditional cultural values, landscape and specific eco-systems preservation as well as co-creation of the rural areas character. During ht e meeting in Luxemburg in June 2003 ministers of agriculture agreed that the EU faring policy should head to strengthen II Pillar of CAP and that its superior aim is to create conditions in which farming will become multifunctional, market balanced and it will be able to sustain rural areas, i.e. to protect the environment and contribute significantly in the rural life vitality[11]. One of the mechanisms which were implemented then was the obligatory modulation which was to assure bigger financial means for the rural areas development. According to this instrument, from January 2005 single payments granted for the EU farmers become gradually reduced[12]. Initially this system covers only countries of the EU-15 and it will come into force in new member states when they reach the level of payments in “old” countries.

In the beginning the modulation system was to counteract the excessive privileges of the largest farms which get non-proportionally big support[13]. Such share of financial means can be regarded as less effective because in large farms further opportunities of productivity growth are heavily limited and additionally by taking into consideration the historical scheme,  we see the situation when the income is sustained without the incentive to improve the managing efficiency. The possibilities to improve it via structural transformation often are over because of a limited number of entities and poor labour sources which could be transferred to other use. It leads to adaptive actions which depend on the improvement of  the EU means absorption instead of efficiency improvement[14]. In this context the modulation must be treated as a tool which transfers some means from bigger to smaller rural households and contributes to the development of the latter so this system should be continued. It is also important that the money achieved in this way was allocated to less developed regions to decrease the differences in rural areas among the member states. In a present shape the modulation does not lead to disproportion levelling because most of the means stays in a particular country.

The European Commission proposes to extend the modulation (2% per year in the period 2009-2012) and to transfer more money to support rural areas from II Pillar. Such attitude is especially important for the EU-15 where further production support in inefficient because the efficiency growth abilities are limited and the progressing costs increase creates no additional value. Whereas in case of new member states there are areas where the added value growth is possible by the development of purely agricultural functions. Therefore the modulation process should be lower there. Otherwise the system can sustain the disproportion of farming support amongst the EU-15 countries and the new members because it will be possible to move the elements of historical payments. That would be against the basic aim of common policy which is the levelling of differences between the EU regions. Therefore for countries such as Poland possible growth of the modulation coefficient is allowed on the condition that the financial means redistribution scale between member states increases on the basis of objective criteria. Simultaneously the modulation in new member states should be implemented gradually, similarly as in the EU-15. Otherwise the income and competitive disequilibrium of national households can appear because they would not reach by 2013 the support level of the EU-15.

No matter the interests of particular member states it should be stated that a further expansion of modulation range and transfer of some financial means to support rural areas is a step in a good direction and the more it is accepted by the tax-payers who finance CAP and who nowadays criticise its shape. They feel that farming should serve the function of a public good which guarantees landscape and cultural values as well as biological diversity. To get those “services” the farmers should be paid for. Otherwise they will quit such an activity and they will get involved in the production of agricultural sources which profitability grows along with the food demand and food prices grow on the world market[15]. Also the fact that the non-agricultural activity significance in rural households income creation is getting bigger and their functioning is dependent not on the production scale but on economic, social and environmental conditions is in favour of transferring some financial means from I to II Pillar[16]. Numerous examples prove that thanks to the support directing it is possible to secure or create new employment in rural areas along with the balanced rural development rules. Thus the environment, landscape and cultural values of rural areas and the development of non-agricultural functions of rural areas are the values which should particularly be taken into consideration when creating the support structures within II Pillar of CAP.

There is another premise which argue for the transfer of financial means from I to II Pillar within the modulation mechanism and which was considered too little when evaluating the CAP functioning. The point is that II Pillar of CAP allows to implement mechanisms which have or can have a positive influence on climate change limitation. There are numerous actions which include in that trend. Those are, inter alia, the actions that consider water management (retention increase, actions against floods), erosion protection, forestation (in the context of retention increase, erosion protection as well as green-effect gases absorption), renewable energy, transport solutions, energy-saving modernisation, biological diversity protection. Properly created rural areas development policy is able to face those challenges. So it is important that CAP includes also problems of the climate change results.

Presented arguments justify modulation mechanisms subsistence, moreover its range expansion, however the change of CAP targets is not possible without the transformation within the financial means redistribution among the member states. It causes problem because the redistribution means “winners” and “losers”. Therefore an open discussion should be held on the CAP functioning changes which started with “Health Check” and which has not been closed yet.

 

 

 

 

Reorientation of market support instruments

Globalisation conditions, negotiations within WTO[17] and the EU expansion of 12 countries require refocus on the CAP instruments, taking into consideration especially beneficial medium-term forecasts for the seed and dairy market. The answer to the present situation in June 2007 the EU member states reached the agreement in the issue of Common Market Organization replacing 21 union sector organisations. The aim was to simplify CAP mechanisms, reformation of managing, increasing the support efficiency and accommodation to new market reality as well[18]. The realisation of this process, according to the European Commission, is to be connected with the elimination of the intervention instruments which are hardly ever used. The Commission’s opinion was that not all the existing market intervention mechanisms are efficient in solving present European farming problems and they do not correspond with present framing conditions. To reach one of the main targets of CAP which is the ability of European farming to compete on the world markets we should create such a support system which will react to the market signals to the highest extent[19].

Assessing the Commission’s postulates concerning the liquidation of some of support instruments it should be noticed that they are heavily the result of the agri-food price growth (crops, milk) on international markets. However the observed economy is likely to be of a short-term character therefore it should not be the justification to limit the market intervention. It must be stressed that the market mechanisms work the way that they are “inactive” in case of high prices. De facto they serve the function of the “safety net” in the situation of a bad economy on the agricultural market. A total abolition of support mechanism would be irreversible and would threaten with a drop of agri-food producers’ incomes. It is worth mentioning that the largest farming competitors (i.e. the USA, Canada, Australia) also use wide range of intervention, the same liquidation of the EU support would lead to the loss of competitiveness. Permanent abandonment of legal opportunities to support and stabilise agri-food prices would be justified in favourable market conditions (which means stable market situation) but those are hard to expect. A new “safety net” should be the more market orientated, protect the producers against losses (i.e. include risk managing mechanisms) and reach the farmers directly. The system should be based on the household income support and not on the support of particular production branches. The priority should be to provide such instruments which would create a stable, environment-friendly agricultural production, not violating WTO regulations.

On the other hand it seems that maintenance of a present level of a price support in the conditions of trade liberalisation (inter alia as a result of WTO actions) is in the long perspective impossible[20]. Therefore gradual abandonment of intervention should include following postulates:

·         preservation of the EU farming competitiveness by ensuring the budget support in this sector and in case of price decrease guarantying extra means for adaption actions;

·         allocation of the means (saved thanks to planned modifications) in other purposes supporting the competitiveness (e.g. promotion and marketing of agri-food products, trainings for farmers, support of technical advances etc.);

·         new solutions should not introduce elements differing the competitive position in various regions and the EU member states.

The support changes should also consider the milk quotas and production limits (e.g. potato starch) and the system of set-asides system. In first case the proposal of milk quotas expiration after 2013 is right. Admittedly, the limits abolition can cause milk prices’ drop but as it seems all those producers who will have modernised their production by then can expect its development. Similarly other production limits should be abolished as well as the set-asides, especially in case of agri-food prices growth and food supply problems in emerging countries.

 

 

A new approach to risk management

A substantial issue discussed within “Health Check” is the concept of risk management in the EU farming. The issue is important because in climate change conditions, trade liberalisation, animals’ and plants’ diseases increase etc. this risk continuously grows and the EU policy heads in the direction of market stabilising instruments abolition of the farming incomes. Also the limits and restrains in using herbicides and pesticides which directly influence the risk growth of agricultural production (vulnerability to diseases, pests, etc.) are significant and they are easily transferable to the price risk. So far the EU farming has used such tools of income stabilisation as animals’ registration systems, vaccinations, the control of brought agricultural products, extraordinary support means which took place in case of e.g. a threat of a bird-flu epidemic[21]. However, it seems that in the perspective of coming years those instruments will have to be supplemented with new methods of risk management which should concentrate mostly on taking actions to limit the risk and to prevent the crisis situation appearance. In this context it seems right to create an insurance system which would sooth not only negative farming income consequences in a new situation but also the effect of natural disasters like droughts, floods etc. which in case of climate changes will become more and more common. Then, a new CAP “safety net” should be not only more market orientated but also protect the producers against losses, i.e. to include risk management mechanisms which would efficiently stabilise the agricultural incomes[22].

The proposals of the European Commission presented during medium-term review head  in the direction of a creation of common reassurance system to solve the problems which occur as a result of natural disasters or climate changes. The insurance is to be limited to crops insurance in case of natural disasters and a mutual insurance against animals’ diseases. The money will come, inter alia, from the modulation (up to 10% of single payments value, member states will be able to transfer to support the agricultural insurance system) and spent within the rural areas development on the condition that they fulfil the criteria of a “green box”. However, it should be considered if such an offer does not violate the competitiveness among the member states. Disproportions can conclude from the fact that the maximum amount of the financial means which the member states can allocate in financing the agricultural insurance system is stated as 10% of a national ceiling of payments granted for particular country. So those countries which historically had a higher limit will be able to spend more on the support and simultaneously they will get a higher refund from the common budget[23]. Because of that it would be advisable to create appropriate financial mechanisms of a structural character, referring to the economically weakest and the most affected regions.

When creating such a system of an agricultural insurance we should remember to fulfil the condition of the insurance commonness which would guarantee a low insurance premium. In case of it being voluntary there is always risk that too few farmers would decide to participate in the system and the means allowed for this purpose will not be fully used. Simultaneously a part of the premium would have to be covered from the public means. The European Commission proposes that the farmer’s share in the premium would be of a 60% and the 40% would be covered form the public means. For Poland and other member states with a fragmented farming 60% of self-contribution seems seriously too much – it should not exceed 50%. Secondly, it should be differed taking into consideration the difference in the financial support per capita, moreover taking into consideration the production volume and assets value. In countries were the farmers thanks to historical rules get higher support, the self-contribution should also be higher and in new member states lower. After some time (when the payments equal) those shares should also be balanced[24]. Moreover, the level of co-financing should differ for the field crops and animal breeding. In the first case it will be easier to separate the influence of weather factors from the subjective than in case of animal breeding. This subjective factor would be e.g. skills and diligence of the producer so-called the management factor. In other words, the results of animal breeding are more vulnerable to management which is the factor dependent on the farmer than in the field crop in which the results are of a random character[25]. Hence, the insurance companies find the field crops more attractive and apply lower premiums. Therefore in case of field production the share in a premium can be higher than in case of animal breeding.

In turn the issue of involving public means in supporting agricultural incomes stays open. Despite violent food prices fluctuation in the past years, within “Health Check” there were no specific reform directions presented. Using the experience of other countries some incentives and stimulus could be created which would prompt the farmers to take care of the income risk  insurance on their own (however that insurance should stay voluntary). Those could be for example tax exemptions from insurance payoffs so the “subsidy” would take place after the damage. It could also be the insurance premium inclusion into the income costs for commercial agricultural producers. Simultaneously the capital market development, especially of the securitisation or re-insurance instruments can limit the amount of public means involved in this range in the near future. When creating the insurance rules against prices fluctuation the experience of other countries like the USA, Canada and Australia[26] which created appropriate instruments should be used. Particularly interesting can be: the income risk insurance on the basis of prices fixed on the stock exchange quotations[27], the indexed insurance with regard to the crops’ level, the insurance on the basis of the amounts deposited in advance on a special bank account[28] etc. Those proposals can be applied in the EU by:

·         directing public means financing the compensation disbursement for the farmers who insured a particular income level but they did not reach it because of the independent reason also because of market fluctuations,

·         the budgetary means support only for those farmers and only when their incomes fall by a stated percent or magnitude with regard to an insured level,

·         securitisation of insurance reassurance and participation in irregular compensations which changes the insurance costs for the farmer.

The insurance would be of a commercial voluntary character which would realise the co-participation rule of agricultural producers in insuring their incomes with certain subsidies of the state. To make the above system work properly an efficient functioning of commodity stock is necessary as well as logistic and financial involvement of insurance and financial sector.

 

Conclusions

Globalisation and integration of the world economy as well as new challenges referring to climate changes, rising food prices and trade liberalisation indicate the necessity of many present CAP directions revision. In this context the medium-term review „Health Check” of the EU budget takes place. The European Commission introduced a number of evaluations and postulates concerning the CAP functioning. Main areas of the discussion focused on four issues: the future of a Single Payment Scheme, rural areas development, market intervention and risk management. Analysing Commission’s proposals regarding the future CAP shape following conclusions can be presented:

·         the EU farming on account of its specific character should still be supported and should not fully be subjected to market rules and simultaneously it must preserve its common character, i.e. common functioning and financing (from the EU budget) rules; any forms of that policy renationalisation, especially within the ways of its financing, would create a threat for the competitiveness conditions in the EU;

·         the support reorientation form market one to the single payments should be assessed positively as a more efficient method in stabilising farming incomes; single payments to a much smaller extent should be linked with the production size and structure and the best destination system would be SAPS because it provides unified competitiveness conditions and simplification of payment management and the farmer itself would be able to foresee the level of support in a long-term because it will independent from the structure and size of production which can fluctuate;

·         a step in a good direction is the strengthening the financing of rural areas via the modulation system; II Pillar plays an important modernisation and pro-development role and further more it meets the social expectations which are shown in agricultural policy requirements, harmonically linked with the policy of rural areas and taking into consideration the issues of food quality and health  as well as bio-diversity of natural landscape;

·         the deregulation of some agricultural markets seems right which is about limiting or abolishing intervention by the market instruments; this postulate also includes the European consumers’ expectations as well as external conditions inter alia existing within WTO; however some range of price intervention should stay and constitute a kind of a “safety net” in case of agricultural economy deterioration; a complete abolition of support mechanisms would be irreversible and would expose the producers to an income drop;

·         in a situation of new challenges it is necessary to implement efficient methods of risk management which should also sooth the negative effects of abandoning present support mechanisms; of such a character the new insurance against natural disasters and animals’ diseases proposed by the European Commission should be; implementation of those instruments is fully justified but on the condition of the insurance being obligatory and its co-financing from the public funds; simultaneously for the agricultural incomes stabilisation new insurance systems against economy fluctuations should be developed using the experience of such countries like the USA, Canada or Australia.

 

References

1.     Analysis of the Health Check Proposals: the reform of the mechanisms for direct support, European Parliament, Directorate General Internal Policies of the Union, Brussels 2008, p. 3.

2.     Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council: Preparing for the "Health Check" of the CAP reform, Commission of the European Communities, Brussels 2007.

3.     Czyżewski A.: The Briefing Note in the third part of the workshop „Market regulation vs. Risk management: how to cope with the instability on the agricultural markets?”, public hearing on 9 June 2008 in European Parliament, the Budget Committee (COBU), Brussels 2008.

4.     Czyżewski A., Kułyk P., Przegląd ważniejszych obszarów Wspólnej Polityki Rolnej UE; rekomendacje dla „Health Check” 2008, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008.

5.     Czyżewski A., Stępień S., Wydatki budżetowe UE w sektorze rolnym – rekomendacje do dyskusji nad „Health Check”,  Zagadnienia Ekonomiki Rolnej 2008/2 [1].

6.     Czyżewski, S. Stępień, Reforma mechanizmu WPR w ramach „Health Check” a potrzeba stabilizacji rynków rolnych UE, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008 [2].

7.     EU Strategy for Biofuels. Impast Assessment, European Commission, Brussels 2006. 

8.     Information of the Polish Government opinion on CAP after 2013, Kancelaria Prezesa Rady Ministrów, Warszawa 2006.

9.     Introduction do Risk Management, Risk Management Agency, USDA, Washington 1997.

10. Matuszczak A.: Dualny rozwój rolnictwa i obszarów wiejskich, [w:] Uniwersalia polityki rolnej w gospodarce rynkowej – ujęcie makro- i mikroekonomiczne (red. A. Czyżewski), Wyd. AE w Poznaniu, Poznań 2007.

11. Modulacja w Polsce – wyliczenia szacunkowe, Fundacja Programów Pomocy dla Rolnictwa, Sekcja Analiz Ekonomicznych Polityki Rolnej, Warszawa 2007.

12. Polska wizja Wspólnej Polityki Rolnej wobec wyzwań oceny funkcjonowania WPR, Ministerstwo Rolnictwa i Rozwoju Wsi, Warszawa 2007.

13. Rębisz W.: Ubezpieczenie dochodów w rolnictwie, Biuletyn Informacyjny ARR 2004/5.

14. Rojewski K.: Zarządzanie ryzykiem w produkcji roślinnej poprzez ubezpieczenia i transakcje terminowe na przykładzie USA, [w:] Kierunki zmian ubezpieczeń produkcji rolnej w Polsce (red. J. Handschke, K. Łyskawa), Centrum Edukacji Ubezpieczeniowej, Warszawa 2008.

15. Stępień S., Dyskusja na temat propozycji Komisji Europejskiej przedstawionych w ramach „Healt Check”, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008.

16. The CAP reform directions within the review planned for 2008/2009 – form the perspective of Poland, Sekcja Analiza Ekonomicznych Polityki Rolnej FAPA oraz Departament Analiz i Strategii UKIE, Warszawa 2008

 



[1] Information of the Polish Government opinion on CAP after 2013, Kancelaria Prezesa Rady Ministrów, Warszawa 2006.

[2] Polska wizja Wspólnej Polityki Rolnej wobec wyzwań oceny funkcjonowania WPR, Ministerstwo Rolnictwa i Rozwoju Wsi, Warszawa 2007, p. 3-4.

[3] Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council: Preparing for the "Health Check" of the CAP reform, Commission of the European Communities, Brussels 2007, p. 3.

[4] A. Czyżewski, P. Kułyk, Przegląd ważniejszych obszarów Wspólnej Polityki Rolnej UE; rekomendacje dla „Health Check” 2008, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008.

[5] A. Czyżewski, S. Stępień, Reforma mechanizmu WPR w ramach „Health Check” a potrzeba stabilizacji rynków rolnych UE, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008.

[6] Despite the fact that the reforms in  2003 introduced the Single Payment Scheme independent from the production size or structure there was a possibility of a partial dependence of the payments on the production size (e.g. in case of oil seeds p to 25%, wheat – to 40%, calves and mother-cows slaughter – to 100%). Within this system it was also possible to so-called mixed system in which a part of the gained payments are the historical payments and the rest  - on the regional basis (such a system was present e.g. in Great Britain). In a further perspective such possibilities are to be limited. See. WPR – Nowoczesna polityka rozwoju rolnictwa i obszarów wiejskich, Fundacja Programów Pomocy dla Rolnictwa FAPA, Warszawa 2007, p. 25-43.

[7] Analysis of the Health Check Proposals: the reform of the mechanisms for direct support, European Parliament, Directorate General Internal Policies of the Union, Brussels 2008, p. 7-8.

[8] Single Area Payment Scheme – SAPS depends on the division of a regular annual financial envelope which qualifies to the reference payment because of the area used for farming and for the payments per each hectare for a particular year. Reference area used for farming is a sum of all the areas in a particular country on 30 June 2003 of fields, long-term crops, green areas and home gardens and used by the owners which fulfil the criteria of minimum area for the payment. The areas which constitute the reference area used in farming must be of a good agricultural culture. Such a system takes place in 10 ne member states. Whereas in SPS the payment per farm is equal an average payment of direct payments received by the farm in reference period 2000-2002. The area entitled to receive the support covers field areas and green areas, however excludes long-term crops, forests and the ground used for non-farming purposes. Receiving the support by farmers depends on obeying the requirements of food safety and environment protection.

[9] In a historical model for each farm a single payment was calculated (separate for a fallow lands and for other fields entitled for the payment) which is dependent on the production size in reference period (i.e. in 2000-2002). Hence, payments calculated per hectare were different for each farm. A regional model of single payments differs from historical model this way that the regional financial envelop is shared among all farmers in the region also those who did not receive the payments in the reference period. Regions are defined by the states members on the objective criteria (e.g. Poland is one region and Great Britain has four regions: England, Wales, Scotland and Northern Ireland) and for all farmers from the particular region a regional payment per hectare applies, uniform for all grounds or distinguished green lands and other entitled grounds. The payment amount received by the farmers are calculated on the basis on the quotient of global payment amount received by all the farmers in particular region or country in reference period and the number of hectares entitled for the payment. This way a single payment in region is stated. This amount is multiplied by the right number of freehold entitled to get the support which refers to the number of general freehold. It shows the magnitude of the single payment received by the agricultural producer.

[10] Analysis of the Health Check…, op. cit., p. 3.

[11] A. Czyżewski, S. Stępień, Wydatki budżetowe UE w sektorze rolnym – rekomendacje do dyskusji nad „Health Check”, Zagadnienia Ekonomiki Rolnej 2008/2, s. 9-10.

[12] In 2005 the reduction was 3%, in 2006 – 4%, and from 2007 it has been 5% of received by the farm single payments, but there are those farmers excluded who annually receive less than 5 000 ˆ of direct support. See  Modulacja w Polsce – wyliczenia szacunkowe, Fundacja Programów Pomocy dla Rolnictwa, Sekcja Analiz Ekonomicznych Polityki Rolnej, Warszawa 2007, p. 2.

[13] For example, the farms which receive more than 20 000 ˆ annually in 2005 in UE-25 absorbed as much as 56,56% if total financial means and constituted only 5,55% of general number of farms. See EU Strategy for Biofuels. Impast Assessment, European Commission, Brussels 2006, p. 7. 

[14] A. Czyżewski, P. Kułyk, Przegląd ważniejszych obszarów…, op. cit.

[15] A. Czyżewski, S. Stępień, Reforma mechanizmu WPR…, op. cit.

[16] A. Matuszczak: Dualny rozwój rolnictwa i obszarów wiejskich, [w:] Uniwersalia polityki rolnej w gospodarce rynkowej – ujęcie makro- i mikroekonomiczne (red. A. Czyżewski), Wyd. AE w Poznaniu, Poznań 2007, p. 107-109.

[17] During the meeting of WTO in Doha, the EU declared the abolition of All export subsidies by the end of 2013 and readiness to open the market for the import from other countries.

[18] Polska wizja Wspólnej Polityki Rolnej…, op. cit., p. 11.

[19] Communication from the Commission…, op. cit., p. 6.

[20] The CAP reform directions within the review planned for 2008/2009 – form the perspective of Poland, Sekcja Analiza Ekonomicznych Polityki Rolnej FAPA oraz Departament Analiz i Strategii UKIE, Warszawa 2008, p. 9-10.

[21] To some extent also the decoupling mechanism itself limits the price risk because it lets the farmer to change the production structure into the direction of the market which gives a higher added value. However, the change in market support instruments and transition to a single payment scheme requires New forms of income stabilisation.

[22] A. Czyżewski: The Briefing Note in the third part of the workshop „Market regulation vs. Risk management: how to cope with the instability on the agricultural markets?”, wystąpienie na sesji Komisji Budżetu i Rolnictwa Parlamentu Europejskiego (COBU) dnia 12 czerwca 2008 r., Bruksela 2008.

[23] S. Stępień, Dyskusja na temat propozycji Komisji Europejskiej przedstawionych w ramach „Healt Check”, Katedra Makroekonomii i Gospodarki Żywnościowej, Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu, Poznań 2008 (maszynopis).

[24] A. Czyżewski: The Briefing Note…, op. cit.

[25] W. Rębisz: Ubezpieczenie dochodów w rolnictwie, Biuletyn Informacyjny ARR 5/2004, p. 58.

[26] Introduction do Risk Management, Risk Management Agency, USDA, Washington 1997.

[27] Such a system is present in the USA with reference to wheat, maize and soya. A farmer who sells grain makes a forward or future transaction. Forward transactions are usually made between the farmer and elevator who is obliged to buy the grain in few weeks on the fixed price accepted on the day of the agreement. Future transactions on the commodity exchange also concern grain deliveries in a stated time but in contrast to forward transaction are rarely put into practise. So future transactions are speculative transactions and their role is to level the price risk See K. Rojewski: Zarządzanie ryzykiem w produkcji roślinnej poprzez ubezpieczenia i transakcje terminowe na przykładzie USA, [w:] Kierunki zmian ubezpieczeń produkcji rolnej w Polsce (red. J. Handschke, K. Łyskawa), Centrum Edukacji Ubezpieczeniowej, Warszawa 2008, p. 82-83

[28] That type of insurance is e.g. in Canada. This is a programme for farms in which a farmer deposits particular amounts on a special bank account and the government pays the same amount. The money is to be withdrawn in special situations of natural disasters which cause the income drop below a stated level of stabilisation coefficient. Whereas Australian Programme of Farms’ Deposit Management enables the farmer in times of good prosperity to deposit a part of income on a programme account. It exempts the agricultural producer from a part of a tax and transfers the rest of it to a lower tax limit. This programme introduces a tax privilege when withdrawing from the fund which in fact substitutes the withdrawals which would take place in case of natural disasters if the fund did not exist. The deposit fund withdrawals which take place in times of an income drop below a stated indexes’ levels are in this programme tax exempted.