Åêîíîì³÷í³ íàóêè/14.
Åêîíîì³÷íà òåîð³ÿ
Marynenko N. Iu.
Ternopil Ivan Puluj national technical university
THE NEW CLASSICAL ECONOMICS AND ITS CRITICS
Rational-expectations
macroeconomics (new classical economics) is a theory that assumes that the
economy is characterized by rational expectations and that business cycles are
due to incomplete information.
Rational
expectations are expectations that are unbiased and based upon the best
available information [1, p. 242]. Real business cycle theory assumes that
business cycles are caused by changes in productivity – in particular, due to
changes in technology and changes in technological knowledge.
The
main features of the new classical economics are:
1. It accepts
model of general equilibrium with no imperfections.
2.
Prices are perfectly flexible, and all markets are permanently cleared (supply is
equal to demand). All markets are
self-correcting.
3. Individuals do not leave prices at
“false” levels since this would result in disadvantages. Equilibrium is optimal.
4. Because present actions entail future
consequences, all agents deliberately form rational expectations. That is, they
exploit all available information at all times since it is in their best
interests to do so.
5. Agents adjust their decisions and
actions so that their plans will be fulfilled optimally when their expectations
are correct.
6. Therefore, expectations (and
information) play the dominant role in determining the state of the economy at
any point in time.
7. They replace the deterministic setting
with a stochastic one. People habitually suffer from expectational errors. These are the errors that explain economic fluctuations.
8. Fluctuations and unemployment can be
traced to voluntary deviations of supply and demand.
9. Thus the business cycle is an
equilibrium phenomenon, and is therefore optimal.
Today,
most macroeconomic theorists, even if they call themselves monetarists or
Keynesians, use rational-expectations theory. Therefore, current theory differs greatly from the models of the past.
For example, most macroeconomic models of the 1950s and 1960s assumed people
used an average of past inflation rates to predict what inflation will be. Consequently, in
these models, the government can always fool people by increasing inflation
above this average level. Believing that
most people can be fooled in the same way year after year is difficult.
Therefore, rational-expectations economists would reject this assumption.
Similarly, they reject any model assuming people can be continually fooled or
mistaken.
Critics
of the theory of rational expectations rests on the following:
1. Expectations are not formed rationally.
If expectations are rationally formed, using all the relevant information
available, then forecasts of prices, interest rates, and output should be
unbiased (with no systematic mistakes), efficient (use all past information),
and consistent (forecasts should not conflict). The bottom line is that errors
in forecasts should be unpredictable. If errors are predictable, then people are
making systematic mistakes and not learning from them. Surveys of consumers and businesses show they make
systematic errors in forecasts. This sort of evidence is not totally persuasive since
what matters for the economy is people’s forecast about the prices and output
that matter most to them and not what they think is happening to the whole
economy. A more general criticism is that using all information may not be
rational. Most people, for example, tie
their shoes by habit without thinking about it. While we may not optimally tie
our shoes every day, a good job is sufficient for most purposes. We all have
various habits and rules of thumb. They save time so we can focus on more
important tasks. Similarly, most business persons may find that focusing on running their
businesses efficiently and using rules of thumb to set prices is more
profitable than spending the time and money to get the best information
possible about the economy.
2. Real
changes may be needed, particularly in unemployment, to force people to change
their expectations. Suppose the best
forecasts predict that if workers do not lower their wages, unemployment will
increase. Given the inaccuracy of forecasts, workers should rationally wait and
see if unemployment does increase before they agree to a lower wage. Consequently,
changes in aggregate demand, even if anticipated, may have real effects.
3.
Because of multiyear contracts, workers may not be able to adjust fully to new
information. Similarly, firms that do
business with each other (for example, farmers, fertilizer makers, seed
sellers, and tractor makers) may be better off adjusting their prices
infrequently since their prosperity is linked to one another. Thus, institutional
impediments may prevent making rapid adjustments even if people’s expectations
are rationally formed.
4.
Recessions cost too much and last too long to be rational. Recall that in
rational-expectations models, people will spend money to predict and prepare
for events. One response to this type of criticism is that recessions cost less
than the output lost since more output can be produced later. A second response
is that the government often causes the recessions, and predicting what the
government is going to do is not just costly but impossible.
Literature
1. Walter J. Wessels. Economics. – 3rd ed. // Barron’s Educational Series, Inc., USA, 2000. – 593 p.