Åêîíîì³÷í³ íàóêè/14. Åêîíîì³÷íà òåîð³ÿ

Marynenko N. Iu.

Ternopil Ivan Pul’uj State Technical University

Some aspects of the rational-expectations macroeconomics

 

Rational expectations – expectations that are unbiased and based upon the best available information. According to the rational-expectations theory high unemployment and recession occur be­cause people are lack of the information necessary to make the work and employ­ment choices necessary to bring the economy to produce up to its potential. Rational expectations say prices would be halved if people were well informed. However, if the event was unexpected, it may take time for them to discover what has happened. People looking for work, for example, may be slow to reduce their wage demands and so will be unemployed by their own choosing. So, until wages drop, a recession occurs.

The central ideas of rational-expectations macroeconomics are illustrated by the following example. Suppose that the government wants to stimulate the economy and does so by increasing the money supply by 10 percent. The first time the govern­ment does this, it works. However, it works by fooling workers and other suppliers into accepting lower real wages. Now suppose the government does the same thing again ten times in a row. By the tenth time, people will have caught on and will raise their wages and prices. Then the 10 per­cent increase in the money supply will no longer work: it will increase prices, not output. The logic of this example leads rational-expectations theorists to reject any theory that states that people can be systematically fooled time after time [1, p. 244].

The rational-expectations theory can be explained by the following assumptions.

1.     People will try to make good forecasts. Businesses need to forecast how well their goods will be sold and at what profit. Workers and consumers need to forecast income and price levels. They try to make the best forecasts, as follows:

a)     they make unbiased forecasts. Rational-expectations theorists believe that people will make random er­rors instead of systematic errors (i.e., they don't repeat the same mistake time after time) when estimat­ing inflation, output, and other economic variables. Any model that assumes people make systematic errors is rejected;

b)    they use the available information well. For example, if the government is following a certain policy (such as stimulating the economy before elections), people notice it.

2. People take steps to avoid being fooled. Let’s consider only workers. In equilibrium, the demand and supply for workers is equal. Now suppose the government increases the money supply unexpectedly. Money wages will rise and workers will ini­tially assume that this represents an increase in their real wages. So they'll work more, and output and employment will go up. However, they have been fooled: when prices go up, the workers will find that only their nomi­nal wages have increased. They have confused a real shock (an unanticipated event that changes real wages or real output) with a nominal shock (an unanticipated event that changes all prices and costs equally, ultimately leaving real wages and real output unchanged in the long-run). Workers will take steps to avoid this happening again. They will demand cost-of-living adjustments in their wage contracts. They will become more aware of government policy and inflation. The next time the money supply is increased, real output won't be affected.

Some texts say that the rational-expectations theory assumes flexible prices and wages. This is not quite correct. The rational-expectations theory assumes that prices and wages will become more flexible if the government keeps trying to fool suppliers and workers into increasing output and employment. Being fooled is costly. However, having flexible wages and prices is also costly. People balance these two costs: when the government tries to fool people more often, people will in turn pay the costs of becoming more flexible.

The results of all of the said above are the following:

1. Anticipated shifts in the aggregate demand (AD) curve have no real effects. If workers know what the government is going to do, they will set their wage contracts so that they are fully employed. In rational-expectations theory, people expect the economy to be at full employment and the price level to be where the AD curve intersects the full-employment level of output (on the long-run aggregate supply curve). Anticipated shifts in AD will not affect output or relative prices. Only the level of prices and costs will change. The government cannot stimulate output by increasing AD in any anticipated or predictable manner.

2. Only unanticipated shifts in the AD curve affect real output.The remarkable conclusion of rational-expectations theory is that shifts in AD affect output only when they trick workers and suppliers into increasing output and employment. For example, an unanticipated increase in aggre­gate demand increases output only because the aggregate supply curve does not shift up with it.

3. Frequent and unexpected policy changes harm the economy. If the government tries to stimulate the economy in any predictable manner (such as when unemployment rises), its policy will become ineffective. On the other hand, if it tries to continually surprise the economy, it may affect output but in negative ways.

An example of how frequent policy changes can harm the economy is that workers, to cope with the greater uncertainty produced by the policy changes, will demand higher real wages. Also, savers will demand a higher real interest rate. As a result, employment and investment will contract, re­ducing output and growth.

Consequently, it is impossible for the government to fool people systematically into increasing output. The effects of continued changes in government policy will be to dull the economy's responses to real changes and to increase uncertainty.

 

Literature

1. Walter J. Wessels. Economics. – 3rd ed. // Barrons Educational Series, Inc., USA, 2000. – 593 p.