THE CRUCIAL ISSUES OF
THE POLITICAL DEBATE
Dnipropetrovsk State agrarian university
Demchuk N.I.,dubrova N.P.
There have been lively political debates about savings banks as long as
this type of financial institutions has existed. The focus of these debates
have been two of the characteristic features of savings banks: They have always
pursued financial as well as non-financial objectives, and until a few years
ago and nowadays at least in some countries they are, in a specific sense,
public banks. I review the debate about savings banks in two ways. First, I
briefly discuss the conventional arguments and present three new arguments for
having this type of financial institution. Second, I review the political
debate as it has developed on the international level, on the level of the
European Union and finally in Germany. I conclude that even though the
political debates of the last two decades have led to rather critical
assessments of savings banks, both the current financial crisis and recent
academic research suggest that this critical position needs to be revised.
Almost as long as
savings banks have existed, there have been debates about why savings banks
exist at all and whether it makes economic sense for the relevant authorities
to accept or even support them, or do what they can to restrict role. There
seem to be mainly two reasons for this debate and its evident liveliness.
First, savings banks differ in several ways from what can be regarded as the
prototype of a bank in a capitalist system, that is, from a bank that is owned
by private shareholders and oriented solely to making a profit for these
shareholders. Second, in many countries savings banks are important competitors
in the market for financial services, and almost naturally, this fact tends to
spur controversy.
Savings banks differ
from privately owned banks because: they are not exclusively and therefore also not strictly
profit-oriented; in a number of countries they are publicly owned or
member-owned; and/or they have a mandate to support their clients and the
communities in which they operate.This list of their special features does not
only suggest why savings banks have been the object of a long and often
controversial political debate, but it also serves to define the term "savings
bank" and thereby to characterize the object of the debate. However, we
should not expect too much from a list of differences between savings banks and
other banks, because the differences between the savings banks of different
countries are considerable, while in many countries the differences between
savings banks and other banks are not at all evident. This fact suggests taking
a closer look at the three differences noted above.
On a conceptual level
it is clear what it means to say that a given financial institution has a
limited profit orientation. It means that the institution is subject to certain
restrictions that do not apply to other financial institutions, or that it
tries to trade-off profit against some other objectives in ways that others do
not. However, it is difficult to determine by simple observation whether a
given financial institution merely tries to maximize its profits over the
longer term and in doing so takes into account how customers, staff members,
competitors, regulators and other stakeholders might react to what it is doing,
or whether its profit orientation is indeed limited in the sense just defined.
For savings banks,
profit is very important. To function well, almost all organizations need to
grow. For regulated financial intermediaries, growth presupposes an increase in
equity; for some types of banks, notably savings banks, self-financing or
retaining profits is the only relevant source of additional equity. Thus,
profit is important for savings banks, even though savings banks are not pure
profit maximizers.
The feature of public
ownership, which applied to almost all savings banks only a few years ago, can
no longer be considered as defining savings banks. In the past 30 years, in
many countries "public ownership" has either been abolished or its
importance has been greatly reduced. For example, by now all Spanish and most
Austrian savings banks have either adopted legal forms of private institutions
and/or they are owned by foundations that regard themselves as private institutions.
Moreover, in those cases in which savings banks are still public law
institutions and in this very specific sense "belong to"
municipalities or counties or other public entities, the property rights of
these entities are much less comprehensive than are those of the shareholders
of a private bank . For instance, these entities do not have the right to sell
"their" savings bank, and the right to take out profits for general
purposes is either nonexistent or tightly restricted.
The third feature, a mandate
to support the economic endeavors of their clients, is also hard to ascertain
empirically, and it is shared by a number of other financial institutions. There
is a fourth feature of some national savings bank systems, such as the German
system. The savings banks in these systems are parts of networks or
federations. While this affiliation is crucial for their business model and the
success of the individual savings banks, it does not undermine their legal and
economic independence in an essential way.
In spite of the
reservations that I have just expressed, taken together, these three or four
characteristic features describe or characterize the "nature" of a
savings bank better than any other list of features. They even help, although,
as shown, in only a limited way, to define a savings bank. Interestingly, the
same four features that serve to characterize savings banks have, over the
years, been criticized again and again, and are therefore at the center of the
ongoing debate.
However, such a list
of characteristic features does not adequately differentiate between savings
banks and other banks, notably cooperative banks and (other) public banks.
Cooperative banks also have a limited profit orientation in the sense defined
above, have "owners" with more restricted property rights, and have a
mandate to serve their clients. Moreover, in many cases they are also
independent institutions and at the same time belong to federations or
decentralized networks that are very important for their business models.
The only fundamental
difference is that all cooperative banks are strictly private institutions,
while in some countries the savings banks are public banks. To make matters
even more complicated, there are also public banks that are not savings banks.
In what follows, I refer to such banks as "(other) public banks".
They share the feature of public ownership with some, but not all, savings
banks.
In view of these
similarities, it is not surprising that much of the political debate about
savings banks also applies to cooperative banks, while a considerable part of
the general political debate about public banks can be directly transferred to
the case of (public) savings banks.
The difficulty of
defining savings banks and of setting them apart from other banks is a problem
that we often encounter in the social science. One way of dealing with it is
not to focus merely on the individual features but to look at a specific
combination of features and define this combination as the "ideal
type" of the object that we want to study and understand. We must accept
that in individual cases, certain features of the ideal type do not apply to a
given practical case. However, this fact does not preclude the possibility of
making meaningful general statements about the "object" that we are
trying to analyze by creating the ideal type, even though the transfer of these
statements to all "real" objects of a given class may be difficult
and open to debate.
Clearly, since trying
to define savings banks precisely and in an operational way is almost
impossible today the political debate about savings banks is inseparable from
those concerning cooperative banks and (other) public banks. The overriding
question addressed in this general debate - and in this paper - is whether and
why it is desirable from a public policy standpoint to have savings banks and
other banks with a social mission.
The paper is
structured as follows. In Section II, I discuss the general arguments for
having public, semipublic, and not strictly profit-oriented banks. Even though
these arguments are rarely perceived as explicitly addressing political issues,
they are in fact highly political, since they revolve around the question of
what the respective roles and strengths and limitations of public policy and markets
are. In Section III, I examine the explicit political debate at the
international level, the European Union (EU) level, and the level of one
country in which the debate has been particularly vivid. The paper concludes
with a summary and a short list of possible future research questions
concerning the role of savings banks in a modern financial system.